Show simple item record

dc.contributor.authorJorda, Óscar
dc.contributor.authorNechio, Fernanda
dc.date.accessioned2020-09-30T19:43:08Z
dc.date.available2020-09-30T19:43:08Z
dc.date.issued2020
dc.identifier.issn978-956-7421-67-1
dc.identifier.issn978-956-7421-68-8 (pdf)
dc.identifier.urihttps://hdl.handle.net/20.500.12580/4885
dc.descriptionThe fortunes of the Phillips curve have ebbed and flowed ever since it was proposed by Phillips (1958). Although its origins are primarily as an empirical regularity, there is now a vast literature that provides more formal justification. In recent times, the Great Moderation and the modern era of central banking brought about the apparent empirical demise of this core relationship. As central banks gained credibility and inflation targeting became widespread, inflation expectations became better anchored; however, the debate is far from settled. Starting in the mid-1980s, several advanced economies have generally experienced the business cycle with barely a ripple in inflation. Paradoxically, a credible, inflation-targeting central bank that cares about the tradeoff spelled by the Phillips curve and sets policy to offset fluctuations in aggregate demand will make empirical estimates of the Phillips curve appear flatter than they really are. The Phillips curve is fundamental for a central bank to evaluate counterfactual policy outcomes. It is not intended to be a forecasting tool.es_ES
dc.description.abstractThe fortunes of the Phillips curve have ebbed and flowed ever since it was proposed by Phillips (1958). Although its origins are primarily as an empirical regularity, there is now a vast literature that provides more formal justification. In recent times, the Great Moderation and the modern era of central banking brought about the apparent empirical demise of this core relationship. As central banks gained credibility and inflation targeting became widespread, inflation expectations became better anchored; however, the debate is far from settled. Starting in the mid-1980s, several advanced economies have generally experienced the business cycle with barely a ripple in inflation. Paradoxically, a credible, inflation-targeting central bank that cares about the tradeoff spelled by the Phillips curve and sets policy to offset fluctuations in aggregate demand will make empirical estimates of the Phillips curve appear flatter than they really are. The Phillips curve is fundamental for a central bank to evaluate counterfactual policy outcomes. It is not intended to be a forecasting tool.es_ES
dc.format.pdf
dc.format.extentSección o Parte de un Documento
dc.format.mediump. 269-316
dc.language.isoenes_ES
dc.publisherBanco Central de Chilees_ES
dc.relation.ispartofSeries on Central Banking Analysis and Economic Policies no. 27
dc.relation.ispartofSerie Banca Central, análisis y políticas económicas, no. 27
dc.rightsAttribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Chile*
dc.rights.urihttp://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/cl/*
dc.subjectINFLACIÓNes_ES
dc.titleInflation globallyes_ES
dc.type.docArtículo


Files in this item

Thumbnail
Thumbnail

This item appears in the following Collection(s)

Show simple item record

Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Chile
Except where otherwise noted, this item's license is described as Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Chile